Why the European Central Bank lacked efficacy to fight against the recent surge in inflation

  • Séverine Menguy Faculté Sociétés et Humanités, Université Paris Cité, 12 rue de l’école de médecine, 75270 PARIS CEDEX 06, France
Article ID: 1626
36 Views, 26 PDF Downloads
Keywords: European Central Bank; monetary policy; inflationary factors; economic activity

Abstract

The paper focuses on the determinants of the surge in inflation between 2021 and 2023 and on the efficacy of monetary policy in fighting against these inflationary tensions. The main role of the European Central Bank is to ensure that inflation expectations remain anchored to a clear target. An active monetary policy can also stabilize future expected inflationary tensions or demand shocks. However, a simple theoretical model can explain the incapacity of European monetary policy to fight against the supply-side factors of inflation in the post-COVID period: inflationary tensions inherited from previous periods, imported from foreign countries (energy and food), or due to higher current or anticipated profit margins. In these cases, a huge increase in the nominal interest rate and a very contractionary monetary policy only risk creating a strong recession, without avoiding inflationary tensions.

References

[1]Attinasi MG, Bobasu A, Manu A-S. The implications of savings accumulated during the pandemic for the global economic outlook. ECB Economic Bulletin. 2021; 5.

[2]Whelan K. Global factors and ECB monetary policy. In: Inflation as a Global Challenge, Monetary Dialogue. ECON Committee, European Parliament; 2022. pp. 73–92.

[3]Bonatti L, Fracasso A, Tamborini R. Tackling inflation at a time of radical uncertainty. In: Inflation as a Global Challenge, Monetary Dialogue. ECON Committee, European Parliament; 2022. pp. 7–42.

[4]International Monetary Fund. The fog of war clouds the European oulook. In: Regional Economic Outlook: Europe. International Monetary Fund; 2022.

[5]International Monetary Fund. Europe’s balancing act: Taming inflation without a recession. In: Regional Economic Outlook: Europe, April 2023. International Monetary Fund; 2023.

[6]Debortoli D, Forni M, Gambetti L, et al. Asymmetric effects of monetary policy easing and tightening. CEPR Press; 2020; 15005.

[7]Beckmann J, Gern K-J, Hauber P, et al. Rising inflation: Transitory or cause for concern? In: Monetary Dialogue Papers. European Parliament; 2021.

[8]Bems R, Caselli F, Grigoli F, et al. Expectations’ anchoring and inflation persistence. Journal of International Economics. 2018; 132. doi: 10.1016/j.jinteco.2021.103516

[9]Ball LM, Mazumder S. A Phillips curve for the Euro area. In: Working Paper Series. National Bureau of Economic Research; 2019.

[10]Gali J. Monetary Policy, Inflation, and the Business Cycle. In: An introduction to the New Keynesian Framework and its Applications, 2nd ed. Princeton University Press; 2015.

[11]Eser F, Karadi P, Lane P R, et al. The Phillips curve at the ECB. In: Working Paper Series. European Central Bank; 2020.

[12]Benigno P, and Eggertsson G. It’s baaack: The surge in inflation in the 2020s and the return of the non-linear Phillips curve. NBER Working Paper. 2023; 31197.

[13]Banbura M, and Bobeica E. Does the Phillips curve help to forecast inflation in the Euro area? In: ECB Working Paper. European Central Bank; 2020.

[14]McLeay M, and Tenreyro S. Optimal inflation and the identification of the Phillips curve. NBER Macroeconomic Annual. 2020; 34 (1): 199–255.

[15]McGregor T, and Toscani F. A bottom-up reduced form Phillips curve for the Euro area. In: IMF Working Paper. International Monetary Fund; 2022.

[16]Bandera N, Barnes L, Chavaz M, et al. Monetary policy in the face of supply shocks: The role of inflation expectations. In: Proceedings of the ECB Forum on central banking, Macroeconomic stabilization in a volatile inflation environment; 26–28 June 2023; Sintra, Portugal.

[17]European Commission. Inflation in the Euro Area and the EU. Available online: https://www.consilium.europa.eu/media/62958/inflation-note.pdf (accessed on 11 August 2024).

[18]European Central Bank. Inflation expectations and their role in Eurosystem forecasting. In: Occasional Paper Series. European Central Bank; 2021.

[19]Coibion O, Gorodnichenko Y, Kamdar R. The formation of expectations, inflation, and the Phillips curve. Journal of Economic Literature. 2018; 56(4): 1447–1491. doi: 10.1257/jel.20171300

[20]Beaudry P, Carter TJ, Lahiri A. Looking through supply shocks versus controlling inflation expectations: Understanding the central bank dilemma. In: Staff Working Papers. Bank of Canada; 2022. pp. 22–41.

[21]Coleman W, and Nautz D. Inflation target credibility in times of high inflation. Economics Letters. 2023; 222: 110930. doi: 10.1016/j.econlet.2022.110930

[22]Gennaioli N, Leva M, Schoenle R, Shleifer A. How inflation expectations de-anchor: The role of selective memory cues. In: NBER Working Paper. National Bureau of Economic Research; 2024.

[23]Boranova V, Huidrom R, Nowak S, et al. Wage growth and inflation in Europe: A puzzle? Oxford Economic Papers. 2021; 73(4): 1427–1453. doi: 10.1093/oep/gpab051

[24]Harding M, Linde J, Trabandt M. Understanding post-COVID inflation dynamics; Journal of Monetary Economics. 2023; 140: S101–S118. doi: 10.1016/j.jmoneco.2023.05.012

[25]Hahn E. The wage-price pass-through in the Euro Area: Does the growth regime matter? In: ECB Working Paper Series. European Central Bank; 2020.

[26]Bobeica E, Ciccarelli M, Vansteenkiste I. The link between labor cost and price inflation in the Euro Area. ECB Working Paper. 2019; 2235.

Published
2024-12-13
How to Cite
Menguy, S. (2024). Why the European Central Bank lacked efficacy to fight against the recent surge in inflation. Forum for Economic and Financial Studies, 2(3), 1626. https://doi.org/10.59400/fefs1626
Section
Review